European Absolutism And Power Politics
Introduction
Louis XIV (1643-1715) of France is remembered best as a strong-willed monarch who reportedly once exclaimed to his fawning courtiers, "L'etat, c'est moi" (I am the state). Whether or not he really said these words, Louis has been regarded by historians as the typical absolute monarch - a symbol of his era. Similarly, historians have often referred to this period, when kings dominated their states and waged frequent dynastic wars against one another as an age of absolutism.
Absolute monarchy, admittedly, was not exactly new in Europe. Since the
late medieval period, rulers had been attempting to centralize their authority
at the expense of feudal nobles and the church. In the sixteenth and early
seventeenth centuries, however, religious strife blurred political issues and
somewhat restricted developing monarchies. After the Peace of Westphalia,
which ended the era of disastrous religious wars, absolutism rapidly gained
popularity because it promised to restore order and security.
Parallel economic developments encouraged the maturing of absolutism. As
the Spanish and Portuguese overseas empires declined, the Dutch, English, and
French assumed commercial and colonial leadership, bringing the European
economy to a second stage of expansion. The commercial revolution, centered in
northern Europe, generated great wealth and brought increasingly complex
capitalistic institutions, both of which furthered the process of
state-building.
When the Peace of Westphalia ended the Thirty Years' War in 1648, it
marked a significant turning point in European history. Peace, after such
prolonged religious conflict and political chaos, renewed possibilities for
centralizing royal authority within European states.
The Shift In Fundamental European Values
The era after Westphalia also saw a fundamental shift in European values.
Although many Europeans - both Protestant and Catholic - were still concerned
about personal salvation, they were now also apprehensive about prospects in
this world. Like their Renaissance predecessors, they enjoyed sensual as well
as aesthetic pleasures; but they put more emphasis on profits, power, and the
need for security. With the memory of war and social upheaval still fresh,
they were inclined toward a belief in order, which shaped their other values.
Secularism And Classicism
Although often subtle, the new secular outlook after 1650 was revealed in
many ways. Despite their many expressed religious concerns, kings now
routinely used religion for secular political ends. The prevailing secularism
was also evident in the elegance, frivolity, intrigue, and sexual license that
characterized royal courts and the private lives of the nobility. In educated
circles, secularism was demonstrated in the growing popularity of science,
with its avowed materialism and its implied refutation of scripture. But even
unlearned common people shared a universal boredom with religious contention,
along with the prevailing desire for stable social conditions.
This yearning for stability and order was clearly demonstrated in the
arts. Earlier, during Europe's era of transitional turbulence, the baroque
style had symbolized flamboyant power and restless frustration. Although the
forms of baroque art and architecture remained popular, they were overshadowed
in this era by a return to traditional classicism. Retaining the baroque
deference to power, the revived classical mode emphasized order in its
discipline, formality, and balance. Classicism owed much to the aristocratic
world where it flourished. It reflected the growing scientific faith in an
ordered universe, and it also expressed the political values of absolute
monarchs, such as Louis XIV, who sponsored many artistic endeavors. Indeed,
the French court led Europe's classical revival.
Classical literature was perhaps best exemplified in the polished and
elegant French dramas of Pierre Corneille (1606-1684), Jean Racine
(1639-1699), and Jean-Baptiste Moliere (1622-1673). The first two were the
great tragedians of the seventeenth century. They followed Aristotle's
traditional rules of dramatic unity but produced works noted for psychological
insights and beauty of language. Usually borrowing their plots from Greek and
Roman antiquity, they often depicted heroes and hereoines as idealized
portraits of contemporary courtiers. Moliere, an author of witty comedies,
contrasted the artificiality of his society with the dictates of moderation
and good sense. All three writers were sometimes mildly critical of
established institutions, although their criticism was not direct enough to
offend patrons.
A similar deference for patronage and authority was revealed in classical
architecture and painting. In these areas, France also led the way. A
state-sponsored culture, begun by Richelieu and Louis XIII in the French
Academy, was continued by Louis XIV in academies of architecture, painting,
dance, and music. The latter's palace at Versailles, with its horizontal
lines, ninety-degree angles, and formal gardens, was copied all over Europe.
So was the work of French court painters, such as Charles Le Brun (1619-1690),
who glorified the Grand Monarch and his society in colorful portraits and
panoramic scenes, emphasizing the common values of elegance and order.
The Capitalistic Ethic
The worlds of art and business, apparently so far removed from each
other, shared common perspectives in this era. Traders and bankers, like most
Europeans after Westphalia, felt a sense of relief and some hope for more
tranquil times in the future. They could now more freely follow their own
capitalistic ethic, which usually placed acquisition of profit over humane or
religious concerns. This commercial secularism was also oriented toward
securing order. Social upheavals obviously hurt business, and a strong state
could promote prosperity in an increasingly interdependent world economy.
By the seventeenth century, particularly after mid-century, this economy
depended upon the exchange of bulk commodities, rather than imported gold and
silver. Eastern Europe and the Baltic supplied grains, timber, fish, and naval
stores. Western Europe supplied manufactures for its outlying regions and for
overseas trade. Dutch, English, and French merchant-bankers controlled
shipping and credit. Plantation agriculture in the tropics, particularly the
cultivation of Caribbean sugar, produced the greatest profits from overseas
commerce. The African slave trade, along with its many supporting industries,
also became an integral part of the intercontinental system.
The New World economy widened European horizons while contributing to
European wealth. New foods, such as potatoes, yams, lima beans, tapioca, and
peanuts became part of the European diet. Tropical plantation crops, such as
rice, coffee, tea, cocoa, and sugar ceased to be luxuries. Production from
European industries, particularly metals, coal, and textiles, also increased
noticeably. Although the European economy slowed considerably in the
seventeenth century, some profits remained enormous, particularly in eastern
Europe and on tropical plantations, where production depended on serfs and
slave labor. Lagging wages in western Europe produced similar advantages for
capitalists, who remained in a most favorable economic position.
Such conditions contributed directly to the development of capitalistic
institutions. As the volume of business rose, great public banks, chartered by
governments, replaced earlier family banks like the Fuggers of Augsburg. The
Bank of Amsterdam (1609) and the Bank of England (1694) are typical examples.
Such banks, holding public revenues and creating credit by issuing notes, made
large amounts of capital available for favored enterprises. Another method of
concentrating capital came with joint-stock companies, such as the Dutch and
English East India Companies, which could pool the resources of many
investors. In the late seventeenth century, exchanges for buying and selling
stock were becoming common, as were maritime insurance companies. Lloyd's of
London, the most famous of these, began operations about 1688 and is still in
business. Such capitalistic institutions regularized business and helped
justify materialistic values in the popular mind.
They also fitted into the emerging state systems. The new capitalism
depended upon overseas trade, which, in turn, required government protection
or subsidy. Government policies affected money, credit, and capital
accumulation. If capitalists needed government, governments also needed them.
Powerful states were increasingly expensive, and overseas trade was a vital
source of revenue. Capitalists could often help monarchs acquire foreign
credit. Military force and bureaucratic organization, so important to rising
states, often depended on capitalistic support. This tacit partnership between
kings and capitalists produced a system known as mercantilism. It was most
typical of France, but all absolute regimes were conditioned by the integrated
European economy. Consequently, both profit and power were compatible
subordinates to order in the European value system.
Philosophical Justifications For Absolutism
The prevailing respect for power was most clearly revealed in theoretical
justifications for absolute monarchy. In the past, defenders of royal
authority had employed the idea of "divine right" in claiming that kings were
agents of God's will. This religious argument for absolutism was still quite
common during the period, but it was supplemented by new secular appeals to
scientific principles.
Bishop Jacques Bossuet (1627-1704), a prominent French churchman and the
tutor of Louis XIV's son, produced a classic statement of divine right theory.
In Politics Drawn from Scriptures, Bossuet declared:
the person of the king is sacred, and to attack him in
any way is sacrilege ... the royal throne is not the throne
of a man, but the throne of God himself .... Kings should be
guarded as holy things, and whosoever neglects to protect
them is worthy of death .... the royal power is absolute ...
the prince need render accounts of his acts to no one ...
Where the word of a king is, there is power ... Without this
absolute authority the king could neither do good or repress
evil ^1
[Footnote 1: Quoted in James Harvey Robinson, Readings in European History, 2
vols. (Boston: Ginn and Co., 1906), vol. 1, pp. 273-275.]
The most penetrating and influential secular justification for absolutism
came from the English philosopher, Thomas Hobbes (1588-1679), whose famous
political treatise, Leviathan, appeared in 1651. The French religious wars,
the Thirty Years' War, and the English civil war of the 1640s inclined Hobbes
to view order as the primary social good and anarchy as the greatest social
disaster. Unlike Bossuet, he did not see God as the source of political
authority. According to Hobbes, people created governments as protection
against themselves, because they were naturally "brutish," "nasty," "selfish,"
and as cruel as wolves. Having been forced by human nature to surrender their
freedoms to the state, people had no rights under government except obedience.
The resulting sovereign state could take any form, but according to Hobbes,
monarchy was the most effective in maintaining order and security. Any ruler,
no matter how bad, was preferable to anarchy. Monarchs were therefore
legitimately entitled to absolute authority, limited only by their own
deficiencies and by the power of other states. ^2
[Footnote 2: Thomas Hobbes, Leviathan (New York: Liberal Arts Press, 1958),
pp. 106-170.]
Absolutism As A System
Unlimited royal authority, as advocated by Bossuet and Hobbes, was the
main characteristic of absolutism. It was demonstrated most obviously in
political organization but also served to integrate into government most
economic, religious, and social institutions. In this section, we will preview
this general pattern of absolutism before assessing its development within
specific European states.
Government And Religion Under Absolutism
Theoretically, the ruler made all major decisions in a typical absolute
state. Although this was not actually possible, chief ministers were
responsible directly to the monarch, and all of their actions were taken in
the sovereign's name. The monarch was officially the supreme lawgiver, the
chief judge, the commander of all military forces, and the head of all
administration. Central councils and committees discussed policy, but these
bodies were strictly advisory and concerned primarily with administrative
matter. All authority originated in orders coming down from the top and going
out to the provinces from the royal capital.
In conducting foreign policy, monarchs identified their personal dynastic
interests with those of their countries. They usually considered the
acquisition of foreign territory to be legitimate and pursued their objectives
in a competitive game of power politics with other monarchs. This competition
required a large military establishment, sometimes involving naval forces.
Rulers sought to form alliances against the most dominant foreign state,
giving little consideration to moral or religious principles. A concern for
the "balance of power" exemplified the new secular spirit in foreign
relations.
Local government was a concern to all aspiring absolute monarchs.
Wherever possible, they replaced traditional local authorities, usually feudal
nobles, with royal governors from other places. Where that could not be done,
local nobles were rewarded so they would support the crown. Sometimes, new
nobles were created and old land grants reassigned. Town governments were
often brought under royal authority through contacts between urban guildsmen
and the king's middle-class servants. Using such means as monopoly grants,
political favors, or bribery, monarchs extended their control over local law
and revenues.
Organized religion remained important under absolutism but lost its
independence of government. Instead of dominating politics, as they had done
earlier, churches - Protestant and Catholic alike - now tended to become
government agencies. Even in Catholic countries, such as France, the king
exerted more political control over the church than did the pope. Although
this had been true of earlier secular rulers, they had faced much more
religious opposition. After Westphalia, monarchs could deliberately use their
clergies as government servants, to enlist and hold popular support. Such
controlled churches exerted tremendous influence in support of absolute
monarchies, not only in the formal services but also in their social and
educational functions.
Mercantilism In The Structure Of Absolutism
In typical absolute monarchies, the regulation of state churches was
accompanied by a system of national economic regulations known as
mercantilism. Although it had originated earlier, with the emergence of modern
states, mercantilism was not adopted generally by European governments until
the late seventeenth century. The expansion of overseas trade, expenses
incurred in religious and dynastic wars, and the depression of the middle
1600s accentuated the trend toward mercantilism as states hoped to promote
prosperity and increase their revenues.
The system attempted to apply the capitalistic principle of
profit-seeking in the management of national economies. "Bullionism" was the
fundamental maxim of mercantilist theory. Proponents of bullionism sought to
increase precious metals within a country by achieving a "favorable balance of
trade," in which the monetary value of exports exceeded the value of imports.
The result, in a sense, was a national profit. This became purchasing power in
the world market, an advantage shared most directly by the government and
favored merchants.
Mercantilists believed state regulation of the economy to be absolutely
necessary for effecting a favorable balance. Absolute monarchies used
subsidies, chartered monopolies, taxes, tarriffs, harbor tolls, and direct
legal prohibitions in order to encourage exports and limit imports. For the
same purpose, state enterprises were given advantages over private
competitors. Governments standardized industrial production, regulated wages,
set prices, and otherwise encouraged or restricted consumer purchases.
Governments also built roads, canals, and docks to facilitate commerce.
Because mercantilists viewed the world market in terms of competing
states, they emphasized the importance of colonial expansion. They regarded
colonies as favored markets for home products and as sources of cheap raw
materials. Colonial foreign trade and industries were controlled to prevent
competition with the parent countries. In pursuing such policies, absolute
states needed strong military and naval forces to acquire colonies, police
them, and protect them from foreign rivals. Thus mercantilist policies often
extended beyond commercial competition to international conflict.
Class Structure Under Absolutism
The class structures of absolute monarchies were marked by clear
distinctions, precisely defined by law. Hereditary feudal aristocrats lost
status unless they acquired an official appointment from the monarch. Such
state nobles owed their privileges to their political service rather than
birth. They often came from merchant families; indeed, the state often sold
titles to wealthy commoners to provide income for the monarch. State nobles
served in public administration, inthe army, the church, or as attendants at
court, where they accented the royal magnificence. They usually received tax
exemptions, pensions, titles, and honors. Their legal rights, dress, and way
of life differed markedly from even wealthy non-nobles.
In contrast, commoners, including middle-class townspeople, paid most of
the taxes required by frequent wars and extravagant royal courts. Peasant
landholders usually owed fees and labor dues to local aristocrats. The poorest
peasants in western Europe were hired laborers or vagabonds; in eastern
Europe, they were serfs. Slavery was rare in western Europe, but provided a
major labor force on overseas plantations.
[See Noble And Peasant: The oppression of the peasantry is the subject of this
engraving, which compares the noble and the peasant to the spider and the fly.
The poor peasant brings all he has to the rich noble, who sits ready to
receive all the produce. From J. Lagniet, Recueil de Proverbes, 1657-63]
While tightening legal class distinctions, absolute monarchies also
further downgraded the status of women. The Reformation had offered some
opportunities for self-expression among women, and before 1650 many women had
assumed temporary positions of leadership. The situation changed after
Westphalia. Although a number of queens and regents were able to rule as
absolute monarchs, most aristocratic women could find recognition only as
Catholic nuns, writers, artists, salon hostesses, court gossips, or royal
mistresses, the latter gaining official status in this era. The status of
commoner women did not fall as much or as quickly, but the advent of early
capitalism and the decline of domestic economies was already excluding them
from many industries and enterprises in the latter seventeenth century.
The Gravitational Pull Of French Absolutism
The popular image of Louis XIV as the Sun King symbolized his position in
France but also implied that French absolutism exerted a magnetic influence
upon other European states. Like all such symbolism, the idea was only
partially true. As much as it was a response to French example, absolutism was
accepted because it promised efficiency and security, the greatest political
needs of the time. Yet French wealth and power certainly generated European
admiration and imitation of the French example.
Typical Satellites Of France
Among the most obvious satellites of the French sun were numerous German
principalities of the Holy Roman Empire. By the Treaty of Westphalia, more
than 300 were recognized as sovereign states. Without serious responsibilities
to the emperor and with treasuries filled by confiscated church properties,
their petty rulers struggled to increase their personal powers and play the
exciting game of international diplomacy. Many sought French alliances against
the Habsburg emperor; those who could traveled in France and attended Louis'
court. Subsequently, many a German palace became a miniature Versailles. Even
the tiniest states were likely to have standing armies, state churches, court
officials, and economic regulations. The ultimate deference to the French
model was shown by the Elector of Brandenburg; although sincerely loyal to his
wife, he copied Louis XIV by taking an official mistress, displaying her at
court functions without requiring her to perform other duties usually
associated with the position.
The era of the Sun King also witnessed an upsurge of absolutism in
Scandinavia. After an earlier aristocratic reaction against both monarchies,
Frederick III (1648-1670) in Denmark and Charles XI (1660-1697) in Sweden
broke the power of the nobles and created structures similar to the French
model. In 1661 Frederick forced the assembled high nobility to accept him as
their hereditary king. Four years later, he proclaimed his exclusive right to
issue laws. A similar upheaval in Sweden in 1680 allowed Charles to achieve
financial independence by seizing the nobles' lands. These beginnings were
followed by the development of thoroughly centralized administrations in both
kingdoms. Sweden, particularly, resembled France with its standing army, navy,
national church, and mercantilist economy. Although Swedish royal absolutism
was overthrown by the nobles in 1718, the Danish system remained into the
nineteenth century.
States In Irregular Orbits
Unlike the Sandinavian and German states, most European governments
resembled Louis' system more in the way they developed rather than in their
specific institutions. As agricultural economies became commercialized,
restricting the developing interests of monarchs and commoners, rulers sought
to ignore their feudal councils and exercise unlimited authority. Some states
in this period had not yet developed as far in this direction as had France;
others were already finding absolutism at least partially outmoded. All felt
the magnetic pull of French absolutism, but their responses varied according
to their traditions and local conditions.
The process is well illustrated by a time lag in the Spanish and
Portuguese monarchies. United by Spanish force in 1580 and divided again by a
Portuguese revolt in 1640, the two kingdoms were first weakened by economic
decay and then nearly destroyed by the Thirty Years' War and their own mutual
conflicts, which lasted until Spain accepted Portuguese independence in 1668.
Conditions deteriorated further under the half-mad Alfonso VI (1656-1668) in
Portugal and the feeble-minded Charles II (1665-1700) in Spain.
The nobilities, having exploited these misfortunes to regain their
dominant position in both countries, could not be easily dislodged. Not until
the 1680s in Portugal did Pedro II (1683-1706) successfully eliminate the
Cortes (assembly of feudal estates) and restore royal authority. With new
wealth from Brazilian gold and diamond strikes, John V (1706-1750) centralized
the administration, perfected mercantilism, and extended control over the
church. In Spain, similar developments accompanied the War of the Spanish
Succession and the grant to Louis XIV's Bourbon grandson, Philip V
(1700-1746), of the Spanish crown. Philip brought to Spain a corps of French
advisors, including the Princess des Ursins, a friend of de Maintenon's and a
spy for Louis XIV. Philip then followed French precedents by imposing
centralized ministries, local intendants, and economic regulations upon the
country.
Aristocratic limits on absolutism, so evident in the declining kingdoms
of Portugal and Spain, were even more typical of the Habsburg monarchy in
eastern Europe. The Thirty Years' War had diverted Habsburg attention from the
Holy Roman Empire to lands under the family's direct control. By 1700, they
held the Archduchy of Austria, a few adjacent German areas, the Kingdom of
Bohemia, and the Kingdom of Hungary, recently conquered from the Turks. This
was a very large domain, stretching from Saxony in the north to the Ottoman
Empire in the southeast. It was strong enough to play a leading role in the
continental wars against Louis XIV after the 1670s.
Leopold I (1657-1705) was primarily responsible for strengthening the
Austrian imperial monarchy during this period. In long wars with the French
and the Turks, Leopold modernized the army, not only increasing its numbers
but also instilling professionalism and loyalty in its officers. He created
central administrative councils, giving each responsibility for an arm of the
imperial government or a local area. He staffed these high administrative
positions with court nobles, rewarded and honored like those in France. Other
new nobles, given lands in the home provinces, became political tools for
subordinating the local estates. Leopold suppressed Protestantism in Bohemia
and Austria and kept his own Catholic church under firm control. In 1687, the
Habsburgs were accepted as hereditary monarchs in Hungary, a status they had
already achieved in Austria and Bohemia.
In the eighteenth century, Maria Theresia (1740-1780) faced Leopold's
problems all over again. When she inherited her throne at the age of
twenty-two, her realm was threatened by Prussia and lacking both money and
military forces. In the years after Leopold's time, the nobles had regained
much of their former power and were again building their own dominions at the
expense of the monarchy. Maria was a religious and compassionate woman, known
as "Her Motherly Majesty," but she put aside this gentle image to hasten much
needed internal reforms. Count Haugwitz, her reforming minister, rigidly
enforced new laws which brought provincial areas under more effective royal
control.
Despite its glitter and outward trappings, the Austrian Habsburg monarchy
was not a truly absolute monarchy. The economy was almost entirely
agricultural and therefore dependent upon serf labor. This perpetuated the
power of the nobles and diminished revenues available to the state. In
addition, subjects of the monarchy comprised a mixture of nationalities and
languages - German, Czech, Magyar, Croatian, and Italian, to name only a few.
Without real unity, the various Habsburg areas stubbornly persisted in their
localism. Even the reforms of Leopold and Maria Theresia left royal authority
existing more in name than in fact. Imposed on still functioning medieval
institutions, it resulted in a strange combination of absolutism and
feudalism.
While Habsburg absolutism wavered in an irregular orbit, Poland was in no
orbit at all. Local trade and industry were even more insignificant in its
economy; the peasants were more depressed; and land-controlling lesser nobles
- some 8 percent of the population - grew wealthy in supplying grain for
western merchants. Nobles avoided military service and most taxes; they were
lords and masters of their serfs. More than fifty local assemblies dominated
their areas, admitting no outside jurisdiction. The national Diet (council),
which was elected by the local bodies, chose a king without real authority. In
effect, Poland was fifty small, independent feudal estates.
Western Maritime States
Although impressed by French absolutism, the agricultural states of
eastern Europe were not yet capable of applying it. At the other extreme,
England and Holland rejected the system, partially beause they had outgrown
it. Yet both states felt the pull toward absolutism in their internal
politics.
The Dutch Republic, in the seventeenth century, was a confusing mixture
of medievalism and modernity. Its central government was a federation of seven
nearly independent states. The stadtholder, as chief executive, led the
military forces but had no control of budget or revenues. Neither did the
States General, the legislative body, which could act only as a council of
ambassadors from the provinces. These were governed by local estates, which
limited the authority of their own executives. The main difference between
this system and Poland's was the political weakness of the aristocracy.
Although rural nobles were strong in some provincial assemblies, the cities,
particularly those in the province of Holland, provided revenues that
maintained the government. Thus wealthy bankers and merchants, who dominated
the major town councils, held the real power.
Even in this political environment, absolutism was a political force. As
successful military leaders, the Dutch stadtholders appealed to popular
loyalties. The House of Orange supplied so many successive stadtholders that
the office became virtually hereditary in the family. By the 1640s,
stadtholders were addressed as "your highness" and intermarried with European
royalty, including the English Stuarts. They created a political machine that
controlled some provincial systems. Arguing for efficiency, they gained the
right to name their councilors as working ministers. From 1618 to 1647 and
again from 1672 to 1703, monarchists controlled the state. In the latter
period, William III built a highly efficient army and centralized
administration.
The Dutch state outdistanced contemporary monarchies in creating the
first northern European empire overseas. Between 1609 and 1630, while at war
with Spain and Portugal, the Dutch navy broke Spanish sea power, drove the
Portuguese from the Spice Islands of Southeast Asia, and dominated the
carrying trade of Europe. In this same period, the republic acquired Java,
western Sumatra, the spice-producing Moluccas of Indonesia, and part of
Ceylon. The Dutch East India Company took over most European commerce with
ports between the Cape of Good Hope and Japan. Elsewhere, the Dutch acquired
the Portuguese West African slaving stations, conquered most of Brazil, and
established New Amsterdam (present-day New York City and the Hudson River
valley) in North America. Dutch commercial and colonial predominance ended
after 1650, but the Dutch Asian empire lasted into the twentieth century.
As Dutch commercial and imperial fortunes declined, England became the
main rival of France for colonial supremacy. The two nations were already
traditional enemies and different in many respects. While France was
perfecting a model absolute monarchy, England was subordinating its kings to
Parliament. Before 1688, however, England also felt the strong attraction of
French absolutism.
The period from 1660 to 1688 was marked by increasingly severe struggles
between English kings and Parliament. England had earlier been torn by fanatic
religious controversy, political revolution, bloody civil war, the beheading
of a king, and rigid military dictatorship. Almost everyone
welcomed the new ruler, Charles II (1660-1685), called back from exile in
France and restored to the throne, with his lavish court and his mistresses.
But Charles, the cleverest politician of the Stuart line, exploited this
common desire for normality to violate the terms of his restoration, which
bound him to rule in cooperation with Parliament.
Charles almost succeeded in becoming an absolute monarch. With the help
of his favorite sister, Henrietta Anne, who had married Louis XIV's brother,
Charles negotiated the secret Treaty of Dover, which bound him to further
English Catholicism and aid France in war against Holland. In return, Charles
received subsidies from France that made him independent of Parliament. He
then used all of his deceit and cunning to create a political machine. This
precipitated a political crisis, forcing him to back down. Ultimately, he
dismissed four Parliaments. After 1681, Charles governed without Parliament,
taking advantage of a strong desire among the propertied classes to avoid
another civil war.
Charles' brother James II (1685-1688) proved to be a more determined
absolutist. Like Charles, he was an admirer of Louis XIV and a known Catholic.
His wife, Mary of Modena, had been persuaded by the pope to marry James as a
holy commitment to save England for Rome. Having been repeatedly insulted by
Protestants at Charles' court, she was now determined to accomplish her
mission. James was quite willing to cooperate. Early in his reign, he
suppressed an anti-Catholic rebellion in southwest England. With his
confidence thus buttressed, he attempted to dominate the courts, maintain a
standing army, take over local government, and turn the English church back to
Catholicism. Most of this was done in defiance of the law while Parliament was
not in session.
In 1688, after James had unsuccessfully tried to control parliamentary
elections, the country was roused to near revolt by the birth of a royal
prince, who might perpetuate a Catholic dynasty. A group of aristocrats met
and offered the crown to the former heir, Mary Stuart, the Protestant daughter
of James by an earlier marriage. Mary accepted the offer with the provision
that her husband, William of Orange, be co-ruler. William landed with an
efficient Dutch army, defeated James, and forced him into exile. This
"Glorious Revolution" pushed England in the direction of limited monarchy.
After 1688, England turned away from French-styled absolutism but
continued to follow mercantilist principles in building a worldwide empire. By
enforcing the Navigation Act of 1651 and other similar laws passed under
Charles, England sought to regulate foreign trade and exploit colonial
economies.
L'Etat, C'Est Moi
Date: 1998